Confronting inequality: basic income and the right to work

By Tim Jackson

Ten years after the financial crisis, inequality in advanced economies is still rising. Tim Jackson presents the findings of a new CUSP working paper to explore potential solutions.

The idea of a citizen’s income originated with Thomas More, who in his work, Utopia (1516), suggested that it could be a means to redistribute wealth when common lands were privatised. More recently, it has enjoyed a resurgence with former Greek finance minister, Yanis Varoufakis, proposing a form of basic income as the solution to the modern dilemma of rising unemployment due to technological advances, in particular robotization and machine learning. For the same reason, the suggestion has become popular amongst the Silicon Valley elite. Just last week, Finland’s basic income trial (the first of its kind in Europe) came under the spotlight with claims that the scheme was to be abandoned as a failure – a claim the Finnish government took pains to deny

Money for no work clearly has its attractions, as Dire Straits pointed out. However, the idea that a universal basic income can remove inequality within society needs a careful examination. Is it more effective in sharing wealth than a tried and tested income tax, where higher income earners are taxed at higher rates? Or than a tax on capital assets, as the French economist Thomas Piketty has proposed? Can any of these measures prevent the systemic inequality that has become more prevalent in advanced economies in recent decades?

These questions lay behind the most recent CUSP working paper on confronting inequality in a post-growth world, in which a macroeconomic SIGMA model was used to explore the dynamics of inequality as the growth rate declines.

Piketty famously pointed out that a declining growth rate can have a damaging effect on the distribution of income. He insisted not only that rising inequality in the US was a direct result of a slowing economy, but also that declining growth rates must inevitably have such an impact. His magnum opus Capitalism in the 21st Century was described as a wake-up call for capitalism. It was also a profound challenge to anyone interested in the prospects of prosperity without growth. A post-growth world with an ‘explosive’ rise in inequality is not a happy prospect.

As it turns out, Piketty made a couple of assumptions in his workings which are critical to the outcome of the analysis. The first of these concerns the behaviour of the savings rate as the growth rate declines with Piketty implicitly assuming it would stay constant. The second key assumption concerns the ease with which it is possible to substitute capital for labour. With constant savings rate and high substitutability of capital for labour, one can easily demonstrate that Piketty was correct. Inequality rises explosively as a result.

It is also possible to see that these conditions look a lot like the world we’re being told to welcome: a small minority of high-tech companies driving an increasingly automated world with a rising capital intensity in which there is less and less need for wage labour. Demand may well stagnate, but as long as the owners of capital have sufficient sway over government to protect their returns, the show can go on. The outcome would be as dystopian as it is possible to be.

Worse still, in these circumstances there is no real consolation in the basic income. In fact, our simulations showed that you could use all three measures (basic income, income tax and capital tax) in combination at rather high rates and you would still end up fighting a losing battle against rising inequality. Perhaps more worryingly for the advocates of the basic income, it turns out to be the least effective of the three measures that were tested in the report, unless it could be introduced at rates considerably higher than those being tested in Finland (and elsewhere).

Fortunately, however, the outlook is not unambiguously bleak. The authors of the report looked into other possible outcomes from Piketty’s assumptions. One possible outcome would be that the net savings rate declines alongside the growth rate. In fact, this outcome may be more likely than one in which the savings rate remains constant: with declining growth and constant savings it is increasingly difficult to protect the rate of return on capital. A decline in returns is unlikely to act as an incentive to invest and will therefore lower the savings rate. At any rate, allowing the savings rate to decline alongside growth immediately allows for inequality to be contained between more reasonable bounds.

There is more good news. With a modest protection on the right to work and fewer incentives to accumulate capital (modelled through a low substitutability between capital and labour) we found that inequality declines ‘naturally’ in the report’s model, even without the impact of measures like the basic income. Taken together with redistributive policies measures, it is possible to eliminate inequality almost entirely, even as the growth rate declines towards zero.

In other words, there are post-growth worlds in which social progress remains entirely possible. It is a comforting outcome in a week when the UK’s quarterly growth rate slumped to a five-year low. It is also a vital finding for those who are less convinced by the growth-obsessed, hyper-capitalism that haunts us today.

Join our mailing list to receive our monthly newsletter
Join
The content of this website is generated by civil society organisations which are either members or partners of SDG Watch Europe. The opinions expressed do not necessarily always reflect the opinions of all members of SDG Watch Europe or the coalition itself. The content of this website is provided for information purposes only. No claim is made as to the accuracy or authenticity of the content and the website does not accept any liability to any person or organisation for the information or advice which is provided or incorporated into it by reference. This website has been produced and maintained with the financial assistance of the European Union. The contents of this website are the sole responsibility of the authors and can in no way be taken to reflect the views of the European Union.